为了正常的体验网站,请在浏览器设置里面开启Javascript功能!
首页 > Normal.dot

Normal.dot

2017-10-24 30页 doc 89KB 13阅读

用户头像

is_954223

暂无简介

举报
Normal.dotNormal.dot 1FDI Flows: The Role of Transparency and Specialization ***Assaf Razin, and Efraim Sadka May, 2004 Abstract We develop a simple information-based model of FDI flows. The relative abundance of ―intangible" capital in specialized industries in the sour...
Normal.dot
Normal.dot 1FDI Flows: The Role of Transparency and Specialization ***Assaf Razin, and Efraim Sadka May, 2004 Abstract We develop a simple information-based model of FDI flows. The relative abundance of ―intangible" capital in specialized industries in the source countries (which presumably generates expertise in screening investment projects in the host countries) enhances FDI flows. But, host-country relative corporate transparency diminishes the value of this expertise, thereby reducing the flow of FDI. The model also demonstrates that the gains for the host country from foreign direct investment [over foreign portfolio investment (FPI)] are reflected in a more efficient size of the stock of domestic capital and its allocation across firms. These gains are shown to depend crucially (and positively) on the degree of competition among FDI investors. 1 We wish to thank Ashoka Mody, Benjamin Bental, Marc Bils, Richard Baldwin, Richard Cooper, Elhanan Helpman, Lance Lochner, Prakash Loungani, and Dani Rodrik for useful comments and suggestions. Special thanks are due to Yona Rubinstein who helped us with the empirical illustration; and to Ariel Burstein who provided us with an illuminating numerical example. We also acknowledge the sponsorship of the European Commission’s RTN project , ―The Analysis of International Capital Markets: Understanding Europe’s Role in the Global Economy.‖ This version was written while the authors visited CES, Munich. * Tel Aviv University, and Cornell University; E-mail: razin@post.tau.ac.il ** Tel Aviv University; E-mail: sadka@post.tau.ac.il - 2 - I. INTRODUCTION Foreign direct investment (FDI) has been growing faster than world GDP, and is becoming a 2major component of foreign investment. We usually observe both one-way flows of FDI, from developed to developing economies, and two-way flows among developed economies. The purpose of this paper is to explore some unique features of foreign direct investment (FDI) associated with host-country transparency relative to the source-country and source-country specialization relative to the host-country, that make this form of foreign investment stand out among the various forms of capital flows, such as foreign portfolio investment (FPI). We develop a simple information-based model, in which the industry specialization in the source country provides a comparative advantage to the potential foreign direct investors in eliciting good investment opportunities in the host country, relative to domestic investors and foreign portfolio investors in the host country. The advantage stems, for instance, from the ability of FDI investors to apply better industry-specific micro-management standards (an ―intangible capital‖). The advantage of FDI investors in their cream-skimming skills is less pronounced when corporate transparency and capital market institutions are of high quality; 3in which case FDI inflows are less abundant. Our model also suggests that the gains from FDI to the host country are reflected in a more efficient size of the stock of domestic capital and its allocation across firms. Domestic firms 2 See the Australian Productivity Commission (2002) for a recent case study. 3 See also Wei (2000), Razin and Sadka (2003), and Albuquerque (2003). - 3 - that are controlled by FDI investors are typically the ―cream" (high-productivity firms). The magnitude of these non-traditional gains from trade that arise in our model depends crucially (and inversely) on the degree of competition among potential FDI investors over the domestic firms. These gains can shrink to zero if there is no such competition altogether. Also, FDI inflows could make the size of the aggregate stock of domestic capital larger than otherwise (under plausible assumptions). This result is consistent with recent empirical evidence. For instance, Borenzstein, De Gregorio and Lee (1998) and Bosworth and Collins (1999) provide such evidence for a sample of developing countries during the period 1978-1995. More recently, in a sample of developing countries, Razin (forthcoming), finds that the effect of FDI inflows on domestic investment is significantly larger than either FPI or loan inflows. He also provides evidence that FDI inflows promote efficiency: The effect of FDI on GDP growth is higher than the effect of other inflows. We view the contribution of the paper only in the development of a corporate-governance channel for the analysis of the determinants of FDI flows. To have a first-pass indication of the relevance of the theory, we provide an empirical illustration of some implications of our model. Thus we caution the reader to view the empirical section as a not being a flat rejection of the model hypotheses. Obviously, our preliminary results possibly reflect many other factors that influence FDI but were not included in the analysis. No attempt has been made for rigorous empirical analysis, because it requires substantially more micro data; that are currently unavailable. The organization of the paper is as follows. Section 2 develops a simple information-based model, which emphasizes the role of host-country relative transparency and source-country - 4 - relative industry specialization in explaining the determinants of FDI and FPI flows. Section 3 compares the benefits for the host-country from receiving FDI inflows instead of FPI inflows. Section 4 provides an empirical illustration. Section 5 concludes. II. FDI AND SKIMMING HIGH-PRODUCTIVITY FIRMS Assume a large number (N) of ex-ante identical domestic firms in an industry. Each firm employs capital input (K), in the first period, in order to produce a single composite good in the second period. As usual, we assume that capital depreciates at the rate δ (< 1). Output in the second period is equal to F (K)(1+ ,), where F (?) is a production function, which exhibits diminishing marginal productivity of capital ( ε bounded below by –1) so that output is always non-negative. For notational ease we also assume that ε is bounded from above by 1. Suppose that the productivity parameter ε is purely idiosyncratic, so that there is no aggregate uncertainty in the model. Consumers-investors are well diversified and will thus behave in a risk-neutral way. We denote by G(?) the cumulative distribution function of ε, ,and by g(?) = the corresponding density function. G(.) At the starting point of the decision process of agents in the first period, the productivity factor (,) of each firm is not revealed with full accuracy. Rather, each firm receives a signal 4,about its productivity, which is common knowledge. The true of the firm is within an ,, 4 One can think of this signal as sort of encapsulated information, provided by up-to-date financial statements. - 5 - ,,interval of ?β around. Formally, given the true value of is distributed according to ,,, the distribution of the productivity factor, conditional on its being in the interval ,,(, the conditional distribution is: ,,,,,,,) ,,,,G(),G(,),,,,. (1) (/),,,G(,,,),G(,,,) ,The conditional distribution denotes the cumulative distribution function of, ,(,,), ,,conditional on the -signal. We assume that the signal is distributed according to the ,, distribution function G(?). ,The firm chooses the level of the capital stock (and investment), denoted by, after the (,)K ,,signalis received, so as to maximize its conditional (on) expected market value. This ,, maximized value is: ,,,,,,,,,,F[K()](1)(1)K(),,,,,,,,V,(),,[K(,),(1,,)K]d,(,/,). (2) ,,0,,,,,1,r,, 5Symbol is the rate of depreciation, is the initial stock of capital, and r is the (1,,)K,0 ,world rate of interest return. The optimalis implicitly defined by the first-order (,)K condition: ,,,,,,,F(K)(1,),(1,),,,,1d,(,/,),0. ,,,,,,,1,r,, 5 Because of the assumption that there is a single composite good, which serves both for investment and for consumption, we implicitly allow the optimal K to be above (1,,)K. 0 - 6 - This expression can be simplified to: ,,,, (3) ,,FK(,)[1,E(,/,)],r,, ,where is the conditional expected value of the productivity factor, given that this (,/,)E ,,factor lies within the interval that is: ,,,,,,,,,, ,,,,,,. (4) E(,/,),,d,(,/,),,,,, Suppose that there is a screening (or search) technology, which, at some fixed cost per firm, can elicit the true value of the productivity factor of the -firm. A potential buyer can apply , the technology after she acquires the firms and gains control of the domestic firm. We assume that foreign direct investors have a cutting-edge advantage over domestic investors in extracting information about the true value of the firm. If foreign direct investors acquire a domestic firm, they can apply their superior micro-management skills in order to elicit the true value of. This advantage stems from some sort of ―intangible capital" (specialized , knowledge) in this particular industry. The basic idea is that firms get involved in foreign operations in order to exploit this unique advantage that they have accumulated over time in their source country. The advantage is modeled here by specifying a lower screening cost for foreign direct investors than for domestic investors. Formally, the cost per firm for a foreign direct investor is C , which is assumed to be lower than C, the corresponding cost for a FD domestic direct investor (i.e., a domestic investor who gains acquires control of the domestic firm). - 7 - If the true value of were to be known, then the firm would choose an optimal capital stock, , denoted by, according to the marginal productivity condition: K*(,) , (5) ,,FK*(,)(1,,),r,, ,Given the signal, a potential foreign direct investor knows that the true value of must lie ,, ,,between and , and that she will be able to elicit the true value of if she ,,,,,,, ,purchases the firm, at a cost C . Therefore, her gross bid price, given the signal, is ,F described by: ,,,,,,,,FK*()(1,),(1,)K*(),,,,,,,,. (6)P,(),,K*(,),(1,,)Kd,(,/,),,0,,,,,1,r,, ,Her net bid price is. Because C is smaller than C, the bid price of the foreign P(,),CFDF direct investor is higher than that of the domestic investor. ,Given the -signal, the value of information to the FDI investor (that is, the value of , ,,eliciting the true productivity of the firm) is. The associated cost is C . In (,)(,)P,VForder to incur this cost, the value of information must exceed this cost. Naturally, one would ,,expect the value of information to rise with. This is because, given the signal , the ,, ,,,deviations of the productivity–independent (,)over the interval (,,,,,,,), from the K productivity–dependent over this interval and, consequently, the deviations of K*(,) ,from over this interval, are magnified by the productivity factor 1+. We (*(,))FK, - 8 - 6,,,therefore assume indeed that rises with. Hence, there exists some cutoff (,)(,)P,V, ,,,level of the signal, denoted by , such that for all, the bid-ask price ,,,,00 ,,,,differenceis negative, and, similarly, for all, the bid-ask price (,)(,),,P,C,V,F0 difference is positive. Thus, all the firms that receive a low-productivity signal will be retained by the original (domestic) owners, and all the firms that receive a high-productivity signal will be acquired by foreign direct investors, who manage to outbid their domestic counterparts. The cutoff level of the signal depends on the screening cost C and is defined by: ', (7) ,,P,(C),C,V[,(C)]00 With FDI investors who can do the screening at a cost C per firm, the cutoff level of the F ,,signal is a function of. ,,,(C)0F0F ,,,The assumption that rises withimplies also that as the screening cost ( C ) (,)(,)P,V,F ,of the FDI investors falls, the cutoff productivity level (that is, ) declines with C, as well. ,F0F This means that with a fall in C, more firms will be acquired by FDI investors. Therefore, a F 7lower screening cost of FDI investors gives rise to a larger volume of FDI inflows. By the same token, as the signal becomes more accurate (that is, as β becomes smaller), the benefit 6 Indeed, Ariel Burstein (2003) provided us with an illuminating numerical example in which ,the bid–ask price difference rises with the -signal, as expected. If the bid-ask price , difference does not rises monotonically with the signal, the equilibrium pattern of foreign and domestic ownership will be more complex, but the qualitative results of the paper regarding the effect of transparency on FDI flows remain valid, as well. 7 We refer to the sum of the acquisition price of the firm and the investment in its capacity (that is financed by the FDI owner) as FDI inflows. - 9 - ,,of the screening technology, which is, declines. We interpret a more accurate (,)(,)P,V signal as an improvement in corporate transparency. The advantage of FDI investors in their cream-skimming skills is less pronounced when host-country corporate transparency 8improves, and FDI inflows are expected to be less abundant. ,,After the signals are revealed, then a firm with a signal, below, actually adjusts its ,,0F capital stock to the signal-dependent, productivity-independent level. But a firm, K(,') ,,which receives a signal above, expects to adjust its capital stock to a productivity-,,0F ,dependent levelwith a cumulative distribution function . The expected value K*(,),(,/,) ,of its capital stock, denoted by is given by: [*(,)/,]EK ,,,,,, . (8) E[K*(,)/,]K*(,)d,(,/,),,,,,, Thus, the total expected value of the stock of capital (before signals are revealed) is: ,1,0FF,,,, (9) KK(,)dG(,)E[K*(,)/,]dG(,),,,,1,,,0F This is our measure of the size of domestic capital. In addition, an FDI investor finances a part of the new investment in capacity from her own (foreign) sources. The other part of the investment comes from borrowing from domestic sources (the host country). We conventionally include the part of the new investment, which is financed from foreign sources, in the definition of FDI inflows. The new expected ,investment of a-firm is given by: , 8 Indeed, these results also hold in Burstein’s (2003) example, albeit with a different stochastic specification. - 10 - ,,,,,,,,- [-,,[K*(,),(1,,)K]d,(,/,),[*(,)/,](1,,)K,(,,/,)EK,00,,,,, ,]. ,(,,/,)(10), We turn now to explain how much of this new investment in capacity is financed by borrowing from domestic sources. We adopt the approach taken by Tirole (2002): ―Borrowing is usually subject to substantial agency costs. The study of the concomitant problem of credit rationing, and the various ways in which firms attempt to reduce its impact, has spawned a large variety of models. Fortunately, these corporate finance models have many common implications…(A) common feature of interest is that borrowing is constrained by the maximal expected income that can be promised to investors. The latter is called ―pledgeable income‖.‖ In our imperfect information set-up, where loans are extended after the productivity-signal , becomes available, but before the true productivity is elicited, we assume that the pledge-, 8able income is calculated as a fraction,, of the productivity worst-case scenario income. , ,That is, the pledge-able income of a - firm, discounted to the present, is: , . (11) ,{F[K*(,',,)](1,,',,),(1,,)K*(,',,)}/(1,r) Note that when corporate transparency improves, and rises, the pledge-able income of a , ,- firm falls. Consequently, debt finance falls as well. , III. FPI INFLOWS VERSUS FDI INFLOWS To understand the unique role of FDI, suppose now that instead of FDI inflows there are only FPI inflows. That is, assume that the world rate of interest (rate of return) continues to prevail 8 For simplicity, we assume that is low enough, so that the expression in equation (11) is , ,smaller than the expression in equation (10). That is, the expected new investment of a - , firm is partly financed by own (foreign) sources of the FDI investor. - 11 - in the home country. Management under FDI ownership, however, may be plagued by the notorious "free-rider" problem. As noted succinctly by Oliver Hart (2000), ―If the shareholder does something to improve the quality of management, then the benefits will be enjoyed by all shareholders. Unless the shareholder is altruistic, she will ignore this beneficial impact on other shareholders and so will under-invest in the activity of monitoring or improving management." To capture this argument in our case, we simply assume that FPI buyers will not be willing to incur the cost of eliciting the true productivity of the firm whose 9equity they purchase. In this case, direct domestic investors acquire and gain control of the firms with high-productivity signals. Domestic and FPI investors will be forced to acquire all the other firms ,,with low-productivity signals. The cutoff level of the signal in this case is ,,(C).,0D0D ,,,,,Because C > C, it follows that [recall thatis increasing in , by ,,(,)(,),P,V,DF 0F0D assumption, and see equation (7)]. Thus, the difference in investment in capacity between the ,,two regimes lies only in the range of signals between and . The capital stock of a ,,0F0D ,firm with a signal below is the same in the two regimes. The expected capital stock of a ,0F ,firm with a signal above will also be the same in the two regimes. But a firm, which ,0D ,receives a signalin-between these two cutoff levels, will invest a signal-dependent K(,'), in the foreign portfolio-investment regime compared to a productivity-dependent 9 In this paper we do not distinguish between foreign and domestic portfolio investors. For an analysis of information asymmetry between these two types of investors, which leads to the home-bias phenomenon in portfolio investment, see Razin, Sadka, and Yuen (1998). - 12 - ,schedule,, with a cumulative distribution , in the FDI regime. Naturally, the K*(,),(,/,) 10latter is more efficient, in the sense that it yields a higher expected return. A. Gains to the Host Country The economic gains from FDI, relative to FPI inflows, consist of the efficiency of investment and the lower screening cost of FDI investors. Note that because the same world interest rate, r, prevails in the home country in the two regimes, it follows that the gains from FDI in our case do not include the traditional gains from opening up the domestic capital market to foreign capital inflows. (Evidently, these traditional gains are present also in the portfolio ,regime.) In the FDI-flow regime the firms with signals above the cutoff signal are ,0F screened; whereas in the FPI-flow regime a smaller set of firms, namely only the firms with '',signals above are screened (recall that ). Therefore, the gains to the host ,,,,0D0D0F country stemming from the efficiency of investment are: ,,0D,,, . (12) GAIN,,P(,)CV(,)dG(,),,,EF,,,0F In addition, for the firms that are screened in the two regimes (that is, the firms with signals ,above), the screening cost is lower under the FDI regime than under the portfolio flow ,0D regime. This gives rise to further gains from FDI, which are: 10 We have assumed that the only advantage of FDI investors over direct domestic investors lies in the search/screening cost. Naturally, if we were to assume that FDI investors can also obtain better information about the true ε (we have assumed that both can accurately elicit ε), then the difference between the two regimes expands to the entire range of [-1, 1] of signals. - 13 - ,. (13) GAIN,(C,C)[1,G(,)]CDF0D Observe that the entire gain, attributable to the lower screening cost of FDI investors is captured by the host country because of the assumed perfect competition among the FDI investors over the domestic firms. This is because competition among FDI investors must ,drive up the price they pay for a domestic firm to their net bid-price [that is, ], P(,),CF ,which exceeds the ask-price of the domestic owners [that is, ; except for the cutoff (,)]V firm (for which the bid price and ask price are equal to each other). Thus, the total gain to the host country from FDI is ,,0D,,,,,,GAIN,GAIN,[P(),C,V()]dG()ECF,,,OF (14) ,,(C,C)[1,G(,)]DFOD Note, however, that in the extreme opposite case of a single FDI investor, a monopoly, she will never offer a price for a domestic firm above the price that will be offered by domestic ,investors, which is, as long as this price is above, or equal, to the ask price of the P(,),CD ,domestic owner, which is Thus, the price at which the foreign direct investor buys a V(,). ,,,,,domestic firm with a signalis Because it P(,),C,V(,),Max[P(,),C,V(,)].,0DD0DD ,,,,follows that in the interval This means that in this interval the (,,,).P(,),C,V(,)D0F0D ,domestic firms are purchased by the foreign direct investor at the ask price Hence, the V(,). ,efficiency gain of investment, GAIN, vanishes. Similarly, firms in the interval [,,1] must EOD ,,be purchased at the price[rather than in the competitive case]. Hence, P(,),CP(,),CDF GAIN vanishes as well. Thus, as expected, the entire gain from FDI accrues to the single C - 14 - FDI investor. To retain some of the gains of FDI a possible remedy for the host country is to impose some sort of a floor to the sale prices of domestic firms. Another partial remedy for the host country is to impose a (source-based) capital gains tax on FDI investors. In the intermediate case of imperfect competition among a few FDI investors but not a strict 11monopoly, the gains from FDI are split between the host country and the FDI investors. B. The Size of Investment in Capacity in the Host Country We have already established that the allocation of the capital stock (its aggregate level and distribution over firms) is more efficient in the FDI regime than in the portfolio regime. Is the capital stock also larger in the FDI regime than in the FPI regime? Recall that the fundamental difference between the two regimes is the screening cost C. Therefore, rephrasing the question one can ask whether a decline in the search cost increases the aggregate stock of capital. In order to answer the question, we write the aggregate stock of capital as a function of C, as follows [see equation (9)]: ,,,()1C0,,,,K(C),K,()dG,(),E[K*(,)/,]dG(,), (15) ',,,1(),Co ,,,where, and are defined by equations (7), (3) and (8), respectively. ,(C),K(,)[*(,)/,]EK0 , Now, differentiate, with respect to C, to get: K(C) 11 Evidently this is an extreme case. If there is an additional domestic input, say labor, the host country still gains, even in the case of a single FDI investor, through infra-marginal gains to domestic labor. However, these gains are sharply smaller than what they could have been in the case of competitive FDI investors. - 15 - ,,d(C)dK(C),0,,, (16)K[(C)]E[K*()/(C)]g[(C)],,,,,,,,000dCdC From equations (3) and (5) we can conclude that: ,, (17) ,,K[,(C)],HE[,/,(C)],00 and . K*(,),H(,) The function, H(?), is defined by: r,,,,,1,H(x)(F). ,,,1x,,, ,1,,The function denotes the inverse of the function, F. Thus, we can rewrite equation (F) (16) as: ,,d(C)dK,0,,,(HE[/(C)]E[H()/(C)])g[(C)] (18) ,,,,,,,,,000dCdC , If the function, H(?), is convex, then it follows from Jensen’s inequality that is dK/dC ,negative (because ). Indeed, one may plausibly assume that H is convex (for d,/dC,00 instance, this is the case with a Cobb-Douglas production function), in which case , . That is: The size of investment in capacity is larger under the regime of FDI dK/dC,0 inflows than under the regime of FPI inflows. IV. EMPIRICAL ILLUSTRATION - 16 - In this section we illustrate empirical implications of our theory. This is done in the context of FDI flows between (host-source) pairs of countries. Our theory is interpreted to suggest that foreign direct investment depends on the accuracy of the productivity signals in the host country, relative to the source country. The more accurate are the signals, the less pronounced is the advantage of FDI investors, and the less abundant are FDI flows to the host country. These signals are proxied by the level of transparency in the corporate sector in each country (see section 2). The latter is in turn represented by the median debt-equity ratio for the sample of firms covered by Worldscope for that country. The reason why we take transparency as positively correlated with the debt-equity ratio is because firms that rely more heavily on debt have to present to their creditors and the public more reliable and 12detailed information about their business. As explained in section 2, a key determinant of FDI flows in our theory is the skimming - cost advantage of FDI investors over other foreign and domestic investors, which stems from ―intangible capital‖ accumulated through industry (or niche) specialization in the source countries. The basic idea is that countries with a high degree of specialization are assumed to have high levels of intangible capital (specialized knowledge) by virtue of the fact that the productive energies of the source countries’ firms have been focused on a smaller number of industries (niches), thereby better exploiting the ―learning-by-doing‖ effects. Hence a higher degree of specialization in the source country, relative to the host country, increases the cost 12 An alternative measure of transparency, the host country creditor rights, is discussed in the Appendix. 13 See Gopinath (2004) for a different application of a search model for a study of FDI flows into developing economies. - 17 - advantage of FDI investors and is expected to generate more FDI flows to the host economy. In the illustration, we use a measure of export-industry concentration as a proxy for intangible capital. The data employed in the illustration are drawn from a sample of 45 countries, both developing and developed countries, over the period from 1961 to 1998. The FDI data are based on the OECD reports of FDI exports from 12 OECD source countries to 45 OECD and non-OECD countries. (More details are available in Mody, Razin and Sadka (2003).) Table 1 provides an illustration of some implications of our theory. The econometric approach is based on Razin, Rubinstein and Sadka (2003) where attention is paid to the problems that arise when FDI flows are ―lumpy‖: FDI flows are actually observed only when they exceed a certain (unobserved) threshold. Therefore, the Heckman selection-bias method is adopted to jointly estimate the likelihood of surpassing this threshold (the ―participation‖ equation) and the magnitude of the FDI flow, provided that the threshold was indeed surpassed (the ―gravity‖ equation). The coefficient of the industry concentration measure is significantly negative in the host country, but not significantly different from zero in the source country, in the participation equation. This is consistent with our hypothesis that a relatively higher industry concentration in the source relative to the host country promotes FDI. (This measure is nevertheless insignificant in the gravity equation for both countries.) The coefficient of the transparency (debt-equity) variable is significantly negative for both countries in the gravity equations, but the magnitude is higher in the host country. This is again consistent with our conclusion that a high level of transparency in the host relative to - 18 - the source country promotes FDI flows. (This variable is insignificant for both countries in the participation equation.) Obviously, the consistency of the data with implications of the theory does not imply that there are no other stories which could explain the correlations found in the data. - 19 - 1, 2Table 1: Relative Transparency and Industry Concentration Panel A Panel B Participation Gravity Equation Host Industry Concentration - 1,98 -0.89 (0.49) (0.85) Source Industry Concentration -0.228 -1.31 (0.76) (1.09) Host Debt-Equity Ratio -0.00098 -0.0067 (0.0007) (0.001) Source Debt-Equity Ratio 0.0006 -0.003 (0.0005) (0.0009) 3Host GDP Per Capita 0.06 0.74 (0.07) (0.10) 3Source GDP Per Capita 2.04 0.58 (0.17) (0.41) Host Average Years of Schooling 0.0078 0.16 (0.03) (0.03) Source Average Years of Schooling 0.064 0.32 (0.039) (0.04) 3Host Population 0.0028 0.64 (0.05) (0.06) 3Source Population 0.774 0.56 (0.07) (0.11) Same Language -0.02 1.36 (0.11) (0.15) Distance -0.007 -0.008 (0.0007) (0.0009) 4Rho -0.513 (0.16) 4Sigma 1.5 (0.09) 4Lambda -0.75 (0.28) Number of Observations 5738 4Log Likelihood -3725 Notes: 1 Specifications include year fixed effects 2 Standard errors in parentheses 3 In logs 4 This variable pertains to the Heckman selection-bias method. - 20 - IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS We develop a model in which foreign direct investors are better equipped than their direct domestic and portfolio counterparts, due to rich experience in the skimming of ―good‖ firms. Employing this advantage, foreign direct investors are able to outbid direct domestic and portfolio investors for the good firms. We emphasize this feature of FDI, which is better hands-on management standards, that entails a cutting-edge advantage over portfolio investors in reacting in real time to a changing business environment. This feature is naturally more pronounced in high-productivity firms, resulting in ―cream-skimming‖ of domestic firms by FDI investors. Note that this mechanism applies both to mergers and acquisitions and to green-field investments. The productivity signal, though, is likely to be coarser in the latter, conveying less information about the true productivity. This makes the FDI investors’ advantage over their domestic direct investors counterparts even more pronounced in the case of green-field investment. We view FDI as distinct from FPI investment with respect to the quality of monitoring the management. Foreign direct investors, by definition, acquire some significant control over the firm they invest in, whereas portfolio investors, plagued by free-rider problems, have no control. Consequently, they can apply hands-on management (or micro-management) standards that would enable them to react in real time to changing economic environments. This feature may stem from ―intangible capital‖ accumulated through a specialization by the - 21 - 13foreign direct investors in a certain niche. Indeed, there is some micro evidence in support of this hypothesis. For example, Djankov and Hoekman (2000) report that foreign direct investors pick the high-productivity firms in transition economies. Similarly, Griffith and Simpson (2003) find that foreign-owned manufacturing establishments in Britain, over the period 1980 to 1996, have significantly higher labor productivity than those that remain under domestic ownership. In addition, labor productivity improves faster over time and faster with age in foreign-owned establishments. 12 The effect on FDI of an alternative measure of transparency, host country creditor rights, is illustrated in the Appendix. 13 See Gopinath (2004) for a different application of a search model for a study of FDI flows into developing economies. - 22 - References Albuquerque, Rui, 2003, ―The Composition of International Capital Flows: Risk Sharing through Foreign Direct Investment,‖ Journal of International Economics, Vol. 61 (2), pp. 353-383. Borenzstein, Eduardo, Jose De Gregorio, and J. W. Lee, 1998, ―How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?," Journal of International Economics, Vol. 45 (June), pp. 115–35. Bosworth, Barry, and Susan Collins, 1999, ―Capital Flows to Developing Economies: Implications for Saving and Investment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 69. Vol. 1, pp. 143– Burstein, Ariel, 2003, Discussion of Ashoka Mody, Assaf Razin, and Efraim Sadka 2003, ―The Role of Information in Driving FDI Flows: Host-Country Transparency and Source-Country Specialization,‖ The North American Meeting of the Econometric Society, Washington D.C (January). Djankov, Simeon, and Bernard Hoekman, 2000, ―Foreign Investment and Productivity Growth in Czech Enterprises," The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 14 (1), pp. 49-64. Gopinath, Gita, 2004, ―Lending Booms, Sharp Reversals and the Real Exchange Dynamics," Journal of International Economics, Vol. 62 (1), pp. 1-23. Griffith, Rachel and Helen Simpson (2003),‖Characteristics of Foreign-Owned Firms in British Manufacturing,‖ NBER Working Paper No. 9573, March. Hart, Oliver, 2001, ―Financial Contracting," The 2001 Nancy L. Schwartz Lecture, Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny (1988), ―Law and Finance,‖ The Journal of Political Economy, 101, 678-709. Mody, Ashoka, Assaf Razin and Efraim Sadka, 2003, ―The Role of Information in Driving FDI Flows: Host-Country Transparency and Source-Country Specialization‖, IMF Working Paper No 03-148, July. Productivity Commission, 2002, Offshore Investment by Australian Firms: Survey Evidence, Commission Research Paper, Canberra, Australia. - 23 - Razin, Assaf, forthcoming, ―FDI Contribution to Capital Flows and Investment in Capacity,‖ in: Ito, Takatoshi and Andrew Rose (eds.), Productivity, East Asia Seminar on Economics (EASE), Vol. 13 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Razin, Assaf, and Efraim Sadka, 2003, ―Gains from FDI Inflows with Incomplete Information," Economics Letters, Vol. 78, pp. 71-77. ———, Efraim Sadka, and Chi-Wa Yuen, 1998, ―A Pecking Order Theory of Capital Flows and International Tax Principles,‖ Journal of International Economics, Vol. 44(1), pp. 45–68). Razin, Assaf, Yona Rubinstein and Efraim Sadka, 2003, ―Which Countries Export FDI, and How Much?‖, NBER Working Paper No. 10145, December. Tirole, jean (2002), ―Inefficient Foreign Borrowing: A Dual-and-Common Agency Perspective,‖ Frank Graham Memorial Lecture at Princeton University, April 11. Wei, Shang-Jin, 2000, ―How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors," Review of Economics and Statistics, No. 1 (February), pp. 1–11. Appendix One may object to the use of debt to equity ratio as the only measure of transparency. In Table A.1 we also use the measure of the host country creditor rights by La Porta et al. (1998). As the negative coefficient of the creditor rights variable indicates, the stronger are creditor rights in the host country, and presumably the better is corporate governance transparency is, the less attractive is the host country to inward FDI flows. - 24 - Table A.1 The Gravity Equations for Inward FDI Flows / Trade ( 1 ) ( 2 ) Host Population 0.417 0.279 (1.52) (1.14) Source Population 0.793 0.791 (3.04)** (3.02)** Host GDP Per Capita -0.881 -1.105 (1.17) (1.63) Source GDP Per Capita 5.15 5.163 (6.47)** (6.51)** Distance 0.513 0.503 (2.40)* (2.37)* Instrumented Telephone Traffic 2.468 2.407 (2.46)* (2.42)* Source Export Concentration 55.032 55.387 (2.86)** (2.88)** (Source GDP) X (Source Export Concentration) -9.778 -9.831 (3.38)** (3.39)** Host Debt-Equity Ratio -0.01 -0.019 (1.47) (2.84)** Host Creditor Rights -0.676 (3.27)** Constant -29.332 -25.71 (4.18)** (3.63)** Number of Observations 324 324 R2 Within 0.1547 0.1542 R2 Between 0.2447 0.4904 R2 Overall 0.1871 0.2966
/
本文档为【Normal&#46;dot】,请使用软件OFFICE或WPS软件打开。作品中的文字与图均可以修改和编辑, 图片更改请在作品中右键图片并更换,文字修改请直接点击文字进行修改,也可以新增和删除文档中的内容。
[版权声明] 本站所有资料为用户分享产生,若发现您的权利被侵害,请联系客服邮件isharekefu@iask.cn,我们尽快处理。 本作品所展示的图片、画像、字体、音乐的版权可能需版权方额外授权,请谨慎使用。 网站提供的党政主题相关内容(国旗、国徽、党徽..)目的在于配合国家政策宣传,仅限个人学习分享使用,禁止用于任何广告和商用目的。

历史搜索

    清空历史搜索